Why Classical, Keynesian, and Marxist Economics Are All Wrong


Why Classical, Keynesian, and Marxist Theories Fail

For over two centuries, humanity has built vast intellectual architectures around economics. From Adam Smith’s invisible hand, through Keynes’s state-managed demand, to Marx’s revolutionary critique of capital, universities worldwide teach these doctrines as if they cover the essence of economic life. Yet all of them remain strangely superficial.

Why? Because they never reach the root of human motivation: the Demand for Recognition (DfR). This neural, inherited mechanism drives individuals, firms, and nations far more than “rational utility” or “class struggle.” Without placing DfR at the center, economics becomes a science of shadows, describing surface phenomena while ignoring the underlying fire.


Classical Economics: The Myth of Rational Self-Interest

Adam Smith and his followers believed markets coordinate self-interested individuals through the “invisible hand.” They assumed that by maximizing personal gain, society would also maximize collective well-being.

  • What they got right: Markets are powerful information systems. They coordinate decentralized actors efficiently.
  • What they missed: “Self-interest” is not simply about material well-being. It is about recognition interest.

When a merchant sought profit in Smith’s time, he was not just seeking bread — he was seeking respect, prestige, and dominance in his community. The invisible hand does not guide self-interest toward harmony; it inflames endless cycles of recognition competition.

Result: Classical economics builds equilibrium models, but recognition has no equilibrium. Human beings never feel “recognized enough.” This endless hunger fuels growth, inequality, and conflict beyond what Smith imagined.


Keynesian Economics: Managing Instability Without Explaining It

John Maynard Keynes emerged after the Great Depression, when classical models failed to explain mass unemployment. Keynes argued that economies are inherently unstable, and governments must manage demand through fiscal and monetary policy.

  • What he got right: Markets are not self-stabilizing. Human behavior creates cycles of boom and bust.
  • What he missed: The true source of instability is the recognition spiral.

People consume not only to satisfy needs but to display status. Firms invest not only for returns but to outcompete rivals. Credit booms and crashes are recognition battles in disguise — speculative bubbles where each actor seeks to “not be left behind.” Keynes’s tools (stimulus, deficits, interest rates) can dampen symptoms, but they cannot cure the underlying addiction.

Result: Keynesianism treats recessions as mechanical failures, but they are in fact psychological eruptions of collective DfR. The state can buy time, but recognition hunger will always resurface.


Marxist Economics: Class Struggle Without Psychology

Karl Marx offered the most radical critique: capitalism is exploitation, and history is class struggle. Workers alienated from their labor will eventually overthrow the bourgeoisie.

  • What he got right: Capitalism produces inequality and exploitation. Economic structures are linked to power.
  • What he missed: Exploitation is not only about property ownership. It is about recognition deprivation.

Workers did not rebel only because they lacked food or wages, but because they were treated as invisible, worthless, Và unrecognized human beings. Likewise, communist revolutions failed not because they misapplied Marx, but because they underestimated DfR. Even in “classless” societies, recognition hierarchies reemerged — party elites, military generals, cults of personality.

Result: Marx thought abolishing property would abolish exploitation. But since the DfR is endless, exploitation reappears in new forms. The Soviet Union did not collapse due to lack of resources, but due to recognition imbalances between elites and ordinary people.


The Common Blindness: Mistaking Shadows for Roots

Despite their differences, Classical, Keynesian, and Marxist schools share a tragic flaw:

  1. They all describe material scarcity — food, money, capital — as the central problem.
  2. They all assume human beings are primarily motivated by survival or comfort.
  3. They all miss the true scarcity: recognition.

Food, shelter, and money have natural limits. Recognition does not. It is an infinite appetite with finite supply. This creates endless competition — between individuals, firms, nations. That is why no economic system has ever found stability.


Eidoism: Recognition as the Root of Economics

Eidoism places the DfR at the center. It claims:

  • All human economic behavior is ultimately recognition behavior.
  • Markets, states, and revolutions are only the theaters where recognition battles play out.
  • Growth is not primarily about survival needs, but about recognition escalation.

From this perspective:

  • Consumption is recognition signaling.
  • Production is recognition offering.
  • Investment is recognition positioning.
  • Policy is recognition redistribution.

A true economics must therefore study how recognition flows shape material flows — not the other way around.


Toward a Recognition Economics Curriculum

If universities adopted this lens, they would teach:

  • Microeconomics of Recognition: How status demand shapes prices and markets.
  • Macroeconomics of Recognition: How recognition bubbles cause instability.
  • Political Economy of Recognition: How recognition deprivation fuels revolts.
  • Development Economics of Recognition: Poverty as exclusion from recognition loops.

And perhaps most importantly:

  • Eidoist Ethics: How to moderate DfR consciously, so societies do not destroy themselves in endless competition.

The Revolution Economics Has Not Yet Seen

Classical economics gave us markets, Keynesianism gave us state management, Marxism gave us critique. But all three fail at the same point: they never opened the black box of human motivation.

The DfR is that black box. It is the hidden neural law behind all economic behavior. Until universities and policymakers acknowledge it, economics will remain a science of symptoms — brilliant in mathematics, blind in psychology.

Eidoism offers a way forward: an economics of recognition. Not to abolish the DfR (which is impossible), but to make it visible, to moderate it, and to design systems where recognition is distributed more consciously and less destructively.

Only then can economics move from being a science of surfaces to a science of reality.


Why the Eidoism View Is Important in Economics

For centuries, economists have tried to build their science on mathematics and statistics, avoiding the messy domain of psychology. They measure flows of money, goods, and capital but rarely ask: Why do humans behave this way at all? By reducing motivation to “utility” or “profit,” economics stripped itself of its human core.

Eidoism restores that missing dimension. It insists that the Demand for Recognition (DfR) is not an optional side factor, but the fundamental neural mechanism behind all economic life.


Recognition as the True Scarcity

Traditional economics begins with the idea of scarcity: finite resources must be allocated among infinite wants. But material resources (food, housing, energy) have natural saturation points. Recognition does not. It is endless.

  • A billionaire never stops accumulating, not because he needs food, but because he craves recognition.
  • A nation does not stop growing GDP once basic needs are met, but because recognition is measured in global rankings.
  • A consumer does not buy a luxury item for survival, but to demand recognition from peers.

Without understanding recognition as the true scarce good, economics cannot explain why growth never ends and why stability is never achieved.


Explaining the Failures of Past Theories

Eidoism shows why past economic theories — Classical, Keynesian, Marxist — fail at their root.

  • They see the surface: prices, wages, capital, class.
  • They miss the engine: recognition.
    This is why economic crises repeat. Each theory applies bandages to symptoms without addressing the deeper drive.

Practical Relevance: Policy and Crisis Management

Recognizing DfR reshapes how we understand policy:

  • Inequality: It is not only a gap in wealth, but in recognition. Poverty is humiliation as much as deprivation.
  • Bubbles and Crashes: They are collective recognition spirals, where speculation is less about profit than about prestige and fear of losing face.
  • Global Trade Conflicts: Nations fight not just over resources, but over recognition of status, sovereignty, and respect.

An economics without DfR treats these as random anomalies. An economics with Eidoism sees them as predictable outcomes of recognition dynamics.


Toward a Science of Balanced Recognition

The importance of Eidoism in economics is not only descriptive but also prescriptive.

  • If recognition is infinite, then chasing it blindly produces endless growth, waste, and conflict.
  • Awareness of the mechanism allows societies to design systems of balanced recognition distribution: cultural recognition, social recognition, creative recognition — not only economic recognition.

This is the path to a post-growth, more sustainable economic order.


Conclusion: The Missing Law of Economics

The Eidoist view is important because it identifies the missing law of economics. Where Smith, Keynes, and Marx stopped, Eidoism goes deeper: to the neural structure of human motivation. Without recognition, economics is blind. With recognition, it becomes a truly human science — able to explain instability, predict crises, and design fairer systems.

In short: Economics without Eidoism is like physics without gravity — elegant on paper, but false in reality.

lên đầu trang
vi